Class Root Cause of Socil Conflict

Topics: Marxism, Karl Marx, Social class Pages: 31 (10511 words) Published: June 1, 2013
The Conflict of Classes: Liberal and Marxist Theories
Ralph Raico Few economists are as celebrated for their knowledge of modern intellectual history as Albert O. Hirschman. Yet in his well-known work The Rhetoric of Reaction, Hirschman is obviously at a loss when confronted with a clear statement of the classical liberal doctrine of class conflict, in Vilfredo Pareto’s Cours d’économie politique (1896-97). Here Pareto speaks of the struggle to appropriate the wealth produced by others as “the great fact that dominates the whole history of humanity.” To Hirschman’s ear this “sounds at first curiously—perhaps consciously—like the Communist Manifesto.” But Pareto quickly “distances himself from Marxism” by using the term “spoliation,” and by ascribing spoliation to the dominant class’s control of the state machine. (Hirschman 1991: 55) Clearly, Hirschman has not the slightest suspicion that Pareto was presenting, in the customary terminology, a liberal analysis that goes back to the first decades of the nineteenth century. Hirschman’s blunder is perhaps understandable if not excusable. Today few ideas are as closely associated with Marxism as the concepts of class and class conflict. Yet, as with much else in Marxism, these concepts remain ambiguous and contradictory. For instance, while Marxist doctrine supposedly

grounds classes in the process of production, The Communust Manifesto asserts in its famous opening lines: The history of all hitherto existing society is the history of class struggles. Freeman and slave, patrician and plebeian, lord and serf, guild-master and journeyman, in a word, oppressor and oppressed, stood in constant opposition to one another...1 On examination, however, these opposed pairs turn out to be, either wholly or in part, not economic, but legal, categories.2 Neither Marx nor Engels ever resolved the contradictions and ambiguities in their theory in this area. The last chapter of the third and final volume of Capital, published postumously in 1894, is titled, “Classes.”3 Here Marx states: “The first question to be answered is this: What constitutes a class?” “At first glance” it would seem to be “the identity of revenue and sources of revenue.” That, however, Marx finds inadequate, since “from this standpoint, physicians

Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, Selected Works in Three Volumes (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1983), I, 108-109. 2 According to Pitirim Sorokin (1947), Marx never presented a coherent conception of social class; the groups mentioned at the beginning of the Manifesto, for instance, include “castes, feudal orders, oppressors and oppressed of all kinds, hierarchies of the medieval corporation.” Marx, in Sorokin’s view, was well aware of this central defect in his theory, and his abruptly terminated chapter in the last volume of Capital was a failed attempt to remedy it. The enduring confusion among Marxists regarding the meaning of class, Sorokin held, may also be traceable to Marx’s own intellectual muddle. 3 Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, III, The Process of Capitalist Production as a Whole, ed., Friedrich Engels (New York: International Publishers, 1967), 885-86. 1

2

and officials, e.g., would also constitute two classes...” Distinct classes would also be yielded by the infinite fragmentation of interest and rank into which the division of social labour splits labourers as well as capitalists and landlords - the latter, e.g., into owners of vineyards, farm owners, owners of forests, mine owners and owners of fisheries. At this point, there is a note by Engels: “Here the manuscript breaks off.” This was not on account of Marx's sudden, dramatic demise, however. The chapter dates from a first draft composed by Marx between 1863 and 1867, that is, sixteen to twenty years before his death.4 Engels's explanation is that “Marx used to leave such concluding summaries until the final editing, just before going to press, when the latest historical...

References: Allix, Edgard (1910) “J.-B. Say et les origines d 'industrialisme,” Revue d 'Économie Politique 24: 304-13, 341-62. Augustin-Thierry, A. (1922) Augustin Thierry (1795-1856), d’après sa correspondance et ses papiers de famille, Paris, Plon-Nourrit. Blanqui, Jérôme-Adolphe (1837) Histoire de l’Économie Politique en Europe depuis les anciens jusqu’à nos jours, Paris, Guillaumin. Calhoun, John C. A Disquisition on Government and Selections from the Discourse, ed., C. Gordon Post (Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill, 1953).
38 38
Carroll, Kieran Joseph (1951) Augustin Thierry (1795-1856), Washington, D. C., Catholic University of America Press. Conway, David (1987) A Farewell to Marx: An Outline and Appraisal of his Theories, Harmondsworth, Eng., Penguin. Cormenin de la Haye, Louis-Marie “Timon” (1846) Ordre du Jour sur la Corruption Électorale, 7th ed., Paris, Pagnerre. Destutt de Tracy, Antoine Louis Claude (1970 [1817]) A Treatise on Political Economy, Thomas Jefferson (tr.), New York, Augustus M. Kelley. Dunoyer, Charles (1880) “Notice Historique sur l’Industrialisme,” in Oeuvres 3 Notices de l’Économie Sociale, Paris, Guillaumin. Euzent, Patricia J. and Martin, Thomas L. (1984) “Classical Roots of the Emerging Theory of Rent Seeking: the Contribution of Jean-Baptiste Say,” History of Political Economy 16 (2) (Summer): 255-62. Grossman, Lionel (1976) Augustin Thierry and Liberal Historiography, Beiheft 15, Theory and History. Halévy, Élie (1965) “The Economic Doctrine of Saint-Simon” (1907), in idem, The Era of Tyrannies: Essays on Socialism and War, R. K. Webb (tr.), Garden City, N. Y., Anchor/Doubleday. Harpaz, Ephraïm (1959) “ 'Le Censeur Européen ': Histoire d 'un Journal Industrialiste,” Revue d 'Histoire Économique et Sociale, 37 (2): 185-218, (3): 328: 57. Hirschman, Albert O. (1991) The Rhetoric of Reaction: Perversity, Futility, Jeopardy, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Hunt, Richard N. (1974) The Political Ideas of Marx and Engels: I Marxism and Totalitarian Democracy, 1818-1850, Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. James, Michael, “Pierre-Louis Roederer, Jean-Baptiste Say, and the Concept of Industry,” History of Political Economy, 9, no. 4 (Winter 1977): 455-75. Kennedy, Emmet (1978) A Philosophe in the Age of Revolution: Destutt de Tracy and the Origins of “Ideology,” Philadelphia: American Philosophical Society. Konrad, George and Szelényi, Ivan (1979) The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power, Andrew Arato and Richard E. Allen (trs.), New York, Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Leggett, William (1984) Democratick Editorials: Essays in Jacksonian Political Economy, Lawrence H. White (ed.), Indianapolis, Liberty Press. Lenin, V. I. (1943 [1917]) State and Revolution, New York: International Publishers. Liggio, Leonard P. (1977) “Charles Dunoyer and French Classical Liberalism,” Journal of Libertarian Studies 1 (3) 153-178 Liggio, Leonard P. (1990) “The Concept of Liberty in Eighteenth and Nineteenth Century France,” Journal des Économistes et des Études Humaines 1 (1) (Spring). Marx, Karl and Friedrich Engels (1963 [1930]) The Communist Manifesto, D. Ryazanoff (ed.) New York: Russell and Russell.
39 39
McLellan, David (1973) Karl Marx: His Life and Thought, New York: Harper and Row. Mehring, Franz (1962 [1918]) Karl Marx: The Story of His Life, Edward Fitzgerald (tr.), Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. Mises, Ludwig von (1957) Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution, New Haven, Yale University Press. Mudge, Eugene Tenbroeck (1968 [1939]) The Social Philosophy of John Taylor of Caroline: A Study in Jeffersonian Democracy, New York, AMS Press. Oppenheimer, Franz (1975 [1907]) The State, John Gitterman (tr.), New York: Free Life. Rothbard, Murray N., (1970) Power and Market: Government and the Economy, Menlo Park, Cal.: Institute for Humane Studies. Say, Jean-Baptiste (1964 [1880) A Treatise on Political Economy, or the Production, Distribution, and Consumption of Wealth, from the 4th ed., C. R. Prinsep (tr.), New York, Augustus M. Kelley. Say, Jean-Baptiste (1815) Cathéchisme d’Économie Politique, ou Instruction Familière, Paris: Crapelet. Skocpol, Theda, Bringing the State Back In, Cambridge, Eng.: Cambridge University Press, 1985. The title derives from an earlier essay by Skocpol. Smithson, Rulon Nephi (1973) Augustin Thierry: Social and Political Consciousness in the Evolution of Historial Method, Geneva, Droz. Sorokin, Pitirim (1947) “Qu’est-ce qu’une classe sociale?” Cahiers Internationaux de Sociologie, 2: 68-71. Stuke, Horst (1976), “Bedeutung und Problematik des Klassenbegriffs: Begriffs- und sozialgeschichtliche Überlegungen im Umkreis einer historischen Klassentheorie,” in Ulrich Engelhardt, Volker Sellin, and Horst Stuke (eds.) Soziale Bewegung und politische Verfassung: Beiträge zur Geschichte der modernen Welt. Stuttgart: Ernst Klett. Thierry, Augustin (1851) Dix Ans d 'Études Historiques, Paris, Furne. Thierry, Augustin, “Preface,” Essai sur l 'Histoire de la Formation det des Progrès du TiersÉtat (Paris: Firman-Didot [1870?]). Welch, Cheryl B. (1984) Liberty and Utility: The French Idéologues and the Transformation of Liberalism, New York: Columbia University Press. White, Lawrence H. (1986) “William Leggett: Jacksonian Editorialist as Classical Liberal Political Economist,” History of Political Economy 18 (2) (Summer): 307-24.
40 40
Continue Reading

Please join StudyMode to read the full document

You May Also Find These Documents Helpful

  • Class Conflict in Kenya Essay
  • Causes of International Conflict Essay
  • Essay about Marx and Class Conflict
  • Essay about Class Conflict in South Africa
  • The Root of Conflict Essay
  • Cultural Relativity: the Root Cause of Conflict in Nigeria Essay
  • Class Conflict Essay
  • Essay on Marxism, Socialism, and Class Conflict

Become a StudyMode Member

Sign Up - It's Free
On se reverra | Le Portrait de Petit Cossette Episode 3 English Dubbed | Bolso Claqué